Up To Date Business Part 17
You’re reading novel Up To Date Business Part 17 online at LightNovelFree.com. Please use the follow button to get notification about the latest chapter next time when you visit LightNovelFree.com. Use F11 button to read novel in full-screen(PC only). Drop by anytime you want to read free – fast – latest novel. It’s great if you could leave a comment, share your opinion about the new chapters, new novel with others on the internet. We’ll do our best to bring you the finest, latest novel everyday. Enjoy!
The man who did more than any other person to develop traffic a.s.sociations and to promote the co-operation of competing railroads was the late Albert Fink. It was his master mind that organised and put into successful operation in 1876 the Southern Railway and Steams.h.i.+p a.s.sociation. The following year Albert Fink succeeded in organising the great trunk lines connecting the North Atlantic seaboard and the States north of the Ohio River. Though smaller traffic a.s.sociations similar to these two organisations had been previously established where but few obstacles had to be overcome, it was Fink who first organised traffic a.s.sociations including all the competing railroads serving large sections of the country.
In discussing the work of traffic a.s.sociations, which are to-day concerns of really enormous magnitude, railway pooling and the cla.s.sification of freight especially demand consideration.
RAILROAD POOLING
Railroad pools are agreements entered into by competing carriers, by which the railroads provide for the division with each other of their compet.i.tive traffic, or of the earnings from that traffic in accordance with stipulated ratios. Thus there are traffic pools and money pools. During the decade preceding 1887, the year when the present interstate commerce law was enacted, most traffic a.s.sociations had the pooling feature, and most of the compet.i.tive railway traffic was pooled, thus eliminating all compet.i.tion in rates.
Pooling agreements have never been legal in this country. Being illegal by the common law, they could not be enforced in the courts.
Section 4 of the interstate commerce law made it unlawful for the carriers subject to the act to pool their freights or the earnings from their freight traffic, and made it necessary for the traffic a.s.sociations to reorganise without the pooling agreements. Until March 22, 1897, it was supposed that the a.s.sociations, without pooling agreements, were legal; but, on that date, in the case of the United States _vs._ the Trans-Missouri Freight a.s.sociation, the United States Supreme Court held that the law of July 2, 1890, popularly known as the Sherman anti-trust law, applied to railways, and made it illegal for railway companies to contract with each other to maintain rates.
Thus at the present time traffic a.s.sociations are permitted neither to contain a pooling feature nor to provide arrangements for the enforcement or maintenance of rates, although the charges may be reasonable and be sanctioned by all the carriers interested. The a.s.sociations may now legally exercise those functions which are connected with the joint business of their members, and they may act as bureaus of information regarding the compet.i.tive traffic. They have no power to make or to maintain rates.
TRAFFIC a.s.sOCIATIONS INCLUDING POOLING SHOULD BE LEGALISED
The best performance of the service of transportation by rail requires the fullest possible co-ordination of the different parts of our transportation system and the largest attainable measure of co-operation among the agents who perform the service. Section 4 of the act of 1887 and the law of July, 1890, as far as the latter relates to railways, are based on an unsound theory. Provision having been made for that kind and measure of governmental regulation of railway rates that will insure reasonable charges, the railways should be permitted to co-operate in rate-making and be given power to pool their compet.i.tive business.
CLa.s.sIFICATION OF RAILROAD FREIGHT
There are thousands of varieties of freight offered to the railroads for transportation. If each cla.s.s of commodities were charged the same freight rate per ton per mile, the charges upon many articles of prime necessity, such as coal, lumber, and grain, would be so high as to prevent their being moved, while the rates on goods of high value per bulk would be much lower than they could readily pay. Cla.s.sification must precede the fixing of rate schedules. The railroads are interested in adjusting their charges to services performed in such a manner as to insure the greatest possible amount of traffic at rates that are properly remunerative. The public is interested in having the necessary revenues of the railroads so levied as to make the burdens as light as possible. To accomplish this a careful grouping of commodities is necessary.
The goods are usually cla.s.sified in five or six large divisions. The official cla.s.sification referred to below has six cla.s.ses. The first cla.s.s consists of articles of high value, the sixth cla.s.s of bulky commodities of low value, such as iron ore, lumber, grain in bulk, etc. In practice, however, the number of cla.s.ses is at least doubled.
Goods of especially high value are made to pay once and a half, double, treble or quadruple the regular first-cla.s.s rate. A commodity is also frequently placed in more than one cla.s.s, the rating of cla.s.sification being lower for car-load lots than for less than car-load s.h.i.+pments. The cla.s.sification is further extended by omitting certain articles from the list of those cla.s.sified. Live stock and coal are ill.u.s.trations of articles to which so-called "commodity," as distinct from "cla.s.sification," rates are given. The individual s.h.i.+ppers are constantly endeavouring to have their goods given commodity rates, and the effort of the railroad companies is to reduce the number of articles excepted from cla.s.sification. Commodity tariffs have been a fruitful source of unjust discrimination.
From this description of freight cla.s.sifications it will be perceived that the main basis upon which the grouping of commodities rests is the relative value of the goods. The gradations cannot, however, be made strictly according to value. The goods are frequently put into a lower cla.s.s than their value would warrant in order to stimulate their production and s.h.i.+pment or to develop the industries depending upon those articles.
At first each railroad worked out a cla.s.sification of its own, and there were practically as many cla.s.sifications as there were railway systems. The disadvantages of this soon became apparent with the development of long-distance traffic. The multiplicity of cla.s.sifications made it difficult for s.h.i.+ppers or purchasers to ascertain in advance what the charges on consignments would be; there was a constant tendency to increase the number of commodity tariffs, and unjust personal and local discriminations were in consequence made more numerous. It became evident that there would be great advantages in having one uniform cla.s.sification for the whole United States. This ideal has not been reached yet, but the number of cla.s.sifications has been practically reduced to three--the official, applying to the traffic north of the Potomac and Ohio and west of the Mississippi; the southern, in force among the railroads in the Southern States, and the western, which obtains in the territory west of the Mississippi River.
This amalgamation of the cla.s.sifications has been brought about chiefly by the traffic a.s.sociations and as the result of the enactment of the interstate commerce law. In order to avoid the discriminations prohibited by that law it was necessary to abandon the system of a separate cla.s.sification for each railway. It is to be hoped that the attainment of the ideal of uniform cla.s.sification will not be long delayed.
THE CONDUCT OF THE FREIGHT BUSINESS OF RAILROADS--TRANSPORTATION PAPERS
The manner in which the freight business is conducted affords a good ill.u.s.tration of the high degree of development to which modern business methods have attained. Freight is accepted by each railroad for s.h.i.+pment not only to all points on its own system, but also practically to every railway station in the country, and even to many foreign cities.
A waybill containing the initials of the number of the car used, the name of the consignor, the name and address of the consignee, the description and weight of the articles sent, the freight cla.s.s and rate of the goods, and the total amount of freight charges, accompanies each s.h.i.+pment and is delivered to the agent at the place to which the goods are s.h.i.+pped.
For the goods thus accepted for transportation, manifests, or "bills of lading," are issued to the consignor, which, like other representatives of property, may be transferred by the owner or may be deposited in a bank subject to draft. Bills of lading are of two general kinds--"straight consignment bills" and "order bills." When a straight consignment bill of lading is issued the goods must be delivered to the consignee or to the person to whom he may order them delivered. An order bill of lading is one that may be transferred upon indors.e.m.e.nt. The following concise description of an order bill of lading is taken from the "Book of General Instructions to Freight Agents," issued by the Pennsylvania Railroad Company:
When freight is consigned to "Order" it is, as a rule, for the purpose of securing the payment at destination of a draft for the value of the property. The draft is usually attached to the bill of lading and sent through a bank for collection from the party at destination, who is to be notified of the arrival of the freight. The payment of the draft secures to the payer the possession of the bill of lading, which must be indorsed by the party to whose order the property is consigned.
XII. RAILROAD RATES
Transportation charges have such a general and vital relation to industrial and social welfare that the problem of the just and equitable distribution of their a.s.sessment is one of paramount economic and political consequence. A consideration of the main factors which influence the railway companies in fixing charges should precede a discussion of the regulation of transportation by the government.
GENERAL FACTORS WHICH DETERMINE RAILROAD RATES AND FARES
The factors which have most weight in fixing schedules of rates and fares are what it will cost to perform the several services, what the services are worth to those for whom they are to be rendered, and the extent to which there is compet.i.tion among rival carriers to secure the traffic concerned. Though on the face of things it would seem that the railways should fix the charges for their various services in accordance with the costs of performing those services, it is neither practicable for them to do so nor is it desirable from the standpoint of public welfare that such a criterion should be adopted. It is impracticable for the railroads to base their charges upon cost of service, because it is impossible to determine accurately the elements which enter into the cost of performing the particular transportation service. The modern railroad is a very complex mechanism, employed in the performance of a mult.i.tude of different services. No railroad official is able to say just how much of the company's total expenses are to be charged against any one particular freight or pa.s.senger service.
The cost of service would be an undesirable basis of rates, because the railroads would derive such a small part of their total necessary revenues from the carriage of goods having a high value in proportion to bulk and weight, that they would be obliged to charge much higher rates than they now do upon the cruder products of the farm, forest, and mine. These products are the basic materials of industry, and the lowest possible rate for their transportation is essential to social and economic progress.
VALUE OF SERVICE AND VALUE OF COMMODITIES
Value of service is a more desirable basis for rates and fares than cost of service. By charging according to value of service is meant that the s.h.i.+ppers of commodities and the pa.s.sengers who travel shall contribute to the railroad's aggregate expenses in proportion to the value which they derive from the transportation service. The rates and fares may cover a part or all of the value of the service obtained. In either case they are fixed with reference to that value and not with regard to the cost involved in performing the work of transportation.
The levy of rates and fares in accordance with this theory, which is usually called "charging what the traffic will bear," is considered by most people to distribute transportation charges properly, because it is claimed that the true measure of a s.h.i.+pper's or a pa.s.senger's ability to pay for a desired service is the value which he will thereby derive. That this theory, nevertheless, does not afford an altogether satisfactory basis of charges, particularly in the freight traffic, may be readily shown.
While it is true that the amount of value added by transportation to goods of low value is less for each unit of weight or bulk than the amount of value which is acquired by an equal weight or bulk of high-priced commodities, yet the _percentage_ increase in value is greater in the case of the goods of low cost. Expensive articles can be carried long distances without adding very much to their cost to the consumers. Measured in their percentages, then, the value of the service of transportation is relatively much lower in the case of the higher-priced commodities. The freight charges on wheat range from twenty to forty per cent. of its farm value, while the rate on shoes is possibly two per cent. of their factory price. That these charges are levied in accordance with the real ability of the articles to pay would be hard to establish.
A PARTIAL THEORY OF RAILROAD FREIGHT RATES
Without attempting in this connection to formulate a complete theory of freight rates, it may be said that there are three factors to which weight should be given in fixing charges: First, _the cost of service_. The total costs of transportation, including a fair return on invested capital, must be covered by total receipts. Furthermore, the minimum rate charged any particular cla.s.s of commodities ought to be sufficient to pay the operating expenses incurred in transporting the goods. Second, _the value of the service_. This fixes the maximum rate that may be charged. Were the railroads to charge more than the service is worth to the s.h.i.+pper the service would not be desired.
Third, _the value of the commodities_. Between the minimum rate fixed by the operating expenses and the maximum charge determined by the value of the service actual rates may vary through a wide possible range. In determining what rates within this range will be theoretically most just and least discriminatory, consideration should be given both to the value of the service and--more than is the case at present--to the value of the articles transported. By doing this rates will be paid by the various articles of freight more nearly in proportion to their ability to pay.
THE EFFECT OF COMPEt.i.tION ON RAILROAD RATES AND FARES
Whatever theory of rates may be accepted as ideally best, it cannot be strictly adhered to under the existing conditions of active compet.i.tion obtaining in the United States. Actual charges have to be fixed and revised to meet the varying circ.u.mstances under which railway traffic is conducted. This compet.i.tion takes several distinct forms. One is that between railways and waterways. A large part of the domestic traffic of the United States has the choice of transportation by rail or by water on the great lakes and the tributary ca.n.a.ls, by the navigable rivers, or by one of the many ocean routes followed by our coastwise commerce.
There is also the compet.i.tion of rival railways connecting common termini or serving the same cities. These forms of compet.i.tion are the ones most frequently noted; but they perhaps exercise a less potent influence over rates than what is known as compet.i.tion through the markets or through the channels of trade. The compet.i.tion between rival centres of commerce and industry--between the Atlantic cities and the gulf ports, for instance, or between the manufactures of New York and Philadelphia and those of Chicago or Cincinnati for the markets of the Southern States, to cite another example--is a force that must be considered in making rates and fares. Even towns served by only one railway and by no waterway enjoy the benefits of this industrial compet.i.tion. Unless the railroad can give the industries in these local towns rates that will enable them to market their products, the industries will decline and the railway will lose its traffic.
An interesting result of the compet.i.tion of roads connecting common termini or joining a common industrial region with seaboard points is that the road whose line is the longest and whose expenses of transportation are greatest is obliged to charge the lowest rate. The short lines can charge more because they compete for traffic under more favourable circ.u.mstances. The lower charge of the longer line is called a differential rate, and it is customary for the shorter or "standard" lines to agree to allow the "differential" line a stipulated differential rate. This is the concession which the standard lines are obliged to make to temper compet.i.tion and to prevent rate wars. The Grand Trunk, running from Chicago to Boston by way of Montreal, is a good example of a differential line, and the New York Central is a good instance of a standard line.
GOVERNMENTAL REGULATION OF RAILROAD TRANSPORTATION
It is a maxim of common law that transportation charges must be reasonable, and the exaction of an unreasonable rate by a public carrier is a common-law misdemeanour punishable by the courts. But when, as the result of severe compet.i.tion of railroads with waterways and with each other, unjust discriminations between persons, between places, and as regards cla.s.ses of traffic--the abuses which const.i.tute the railway question--became prevalent, the common-law provisions applying to railway charges were given statutory form and were supplemented and extended by such legislation as the circ.u.mstances peculiar to the situation seemed to demand. The comprehensive railway- and ca.n.a.l-traffic act pa.s.sed by Great Britain in 1854 has been the model adopted for much of the railway legislation in the United States.
The Const.i.tution of the United States gives Congress power to regulate commerce "among the several States," but the jurisdiction over intrastate traffic lies with the State governments. The States began to pa.s.s general laws for the regulation of railroads fully twenty years before Congress acted, and two thirds of the States have established commissions to administer those laws.
THE INTERSTATE COMMERCE LAW
After fifteen years of agitation and investigation the existing interstate commerce law was enacted in 1887. The law prohibits unreasonable rates and unjust discriminations between persons, places, and cla.s.ses of traffic, prohibits pooling agreements, provides penalties for the violation of the law, and establishes a commission of five men to administer and enforce the statute. Fortunately for the commission and for the country the first chairman of that body was the eminent jurist, Thomas M. Cooley, whose master mind did much to give vitality to the law.
During the first five years after the law was pa.s.sed it secured a fairly efficient regulation of interstate railway commerce, but recent decisions of the United States Supreme Court have so weakened the law that at present the commission has very little power. The commission can investigate complaints and make reports, it can collect statistical information, it can and does informally adjust many differences between s.h.i.+ppers and carriers; but, to quote from the last report of the commission, "it has ceased to be a body for the regulation of interstate carriers." Legislation to amend and strengthen the interstate commerce law is urgently needed.
[Ill.u.s.tration: Judge Thomas M. Cooley. (First chairman of the interstate commerce commission.)]
XIII. STOCK AND PRODUCE EXCHANGES
THE STOCK EXCHANGE
The stock exchanges of the world must not be considered simply as noisy congregations of brokers speculating in securities under the guise of legitimate business. They really play an important and necessary part in the financial mechanism of the country, and are instruments of enormous value in subdividing and distributing capital, and in directing its employment in great commercial and industrial enterprises.
The largest stock exchange of the world is that of London. It is not only the centre of the English market for stocks and securities but, like the Bank of England, it is linked internationally with nearly all the financial centres of the world. Almost every reputable security is marketable in London, either through the ordinary channels provided by arbitrage dealers, who buy in the cheaper and sell in the dearer markets, or through the agency of trusts and investment concerns. The magnitude and extent of the financial resources of the London Stock Exchange are enormous. Its advantages to the business public outweigh altogether the drawbacks imposed by the too-speculative spirit of mankind. It is a great business barometer, extremely sensitive to all conditions likely to disturb the world's finances. The London Stock Exchange has scarcely more than one hundred years of history. In the early part of the century the elder Rothschild was one of the giants "on 'change," and it was in this business that he ama.s.sed the great fortune which makes the name of his house a synonym for money power.
The members.h.i.+p of the London exchange is not limited to a fixed number, as in Paris and New York. In the Paris Bourse all agents are strictly forbidden to trade on their own account.
[Ill.u.s.tration: The Paris Bourse.]
The New York Stock Exchange was formed in 1792. There are 1100 members. Members are elected and must be nominated by two men who will say that they would accept the uncertified cheque of the nominee for $20,000. The initiation fee is $20,000. Members.h.i.+ps have sold as high as $32,500, and the market value of a seat on the Exchange varies only slightly from year to year.
[Ill.u.s.tration: Interior view of New York Stock Exchange.]
There are stock exchanges in all large cities, and scattered throughout the country in convenient centres are grain and produce exchanges, cotton exchanges, petroleum exchanges, etc. These exchanges are really the central markets for the commodities they represent.
Commodity exchanges deal in actual products, even though the dealers handle nothing but warehouse receipts or promises to deliver. Stock exchanges deal in credits and securities, which may or may not have a tangible value back of them.
Up To Date Business Part 17
You're reading novel Up To Date Business Part 17 online at LightNovelFree.com. You can use the follow function to bookmark your favorite novel ( Only for registered users ). If you find any errors ( broken links, can't load photos, etc.. ), Please let us know so we can fix it as soon as possible. And when you start a conversation or debate about a certain topic with other people, please do not offend them just because you don't like their opinions.
Up To Date Business Part 17 summary
You're reading Up To Date Business Part 17. This novel has been translated by Updating. Author: Seymour Eaton already has 495 views.
It's great if you read and follow any novel on our website. We promise you that we'll bring you the latest, hottest novel everyday and FREE.
LightNovelFree.com is a most smartest website for reading novel online, it can automatic resize images to fit your pc screen, even on your mobile. Experience now by using your smartphone and access to LightNovelFree.com
- Related chapter:
- Up To Date Business Part 16
- Up To Date Business Part 18